Low carbon economy index 2011

Transcrição

Low carbon economy index 2011
www.pwc.co.uk
Counting the cost
of carbon
Low carbon
economy index 2011
November 2011
Low carbon economy index 2011
Foreword
This is the third edition of PwC’s Low Carbon Economy Index, but may be the first where the data points
unambiguously towards one conclusion.
The results of the 2009 Index gave grounds for cautious optimism. We had got off to a slow start, no question.
Since 2000, globally, we had improved carbon efficiency only 0.8% a year on average, against the 2% a year that
was needed to reduce carbon by 80% by 2050 and so limit global warming to 2 degrees. So there was a low
carbon challenge. We needed to step up our improvements in carbon efficiency. But the annual improvement
needed at that stage was still only 3.4% per year, a figure that a number of OECD nations had achieved over
sustained periods. On top of that was the regulatory and investment stimulus expected from Copenhagen. It
was all to play for.
In year two, the case for optimism was less clear. Despite Copenhagen, against the 3.4% improvement needed,
globally, we had only managed to achieve a 0.7% reduction in carbon intensity over the year, less than the 0.8%
achieved in the previous year. Our rate of decarbonisation had slowed.
This year, 2011, the results are the starkest yet.
For the first time we have made no improvement in our rate of decarbonisation. We have in fact increased the
carbon intensity of growth. The economic recovery, where it has occurred, has been dirty. Even where there has
been growth in OECD countries during the global financial crisis, it has not been decoupled from carbon. The
rapid growth of high carbon intensive emerging economies in this period, has also pushed up the average
carbon intensity of the global economy.
In sum, the 2011 PwC Low Carbon Economy Index shows that the G20 economies have moved from travelling
too slowly in the right direction, to travelling in the wrong direction. The annual percentage reduction now
required is 4.8% per year, a figure in excess of what has been proven to be historically sustainable. The results
call into question the current likelihood of our global decarbonisation ever happening rapidly enough to avoid 2
degrees of global warming. But 2011 has thrown up a second challenge as well. The events of the Arab Spring
have shown the social, economic and political necessity of delivering not just low carbon growth, but growth
that delivers on the basic needs, including power, of the billions at the bottom of the pyramid.
It's around this emerging and complex challenge, delivering inclusive green growth at scale, that this year's Low
Carbon Economy Index aims to give some context.
Leo Johnson
Partner, Sustainability & Climate Change, PwC UK
PwC
Page 2 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Table of Contents
Foreword
2
1.
LCEI results and analysis
6
2.
The financing gap
14
2.1
The UK
14
2.2
South Africa
16
3.
Moving towards the low carbon economy
17
3.1
Win-win opportunities
17
3.2
Addressing key regulatory and infrastructure barriers
18
3.3
Innovative finance
19
4.
Concluding remarks
21
PwC
Page 3 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Key messages
Last year the carbon intensity of the world economy
increased. For the first time in many years, this reversed
the trend of gradual decarbonisation of economies.
Instead of moving too slowly in the right direction, we are
now moving in the wrong direction.
Achieving the 2 degrees Celsius goal will now require
reductions in carbon intensity of at least 4.8% every year
until 2050. This compares with a 2% per year reduction in
carbon intensity, to meet this goal, had we started in
2000.
It is only in exceptional circumstances that this rate of
decarbonisation has been achieved in the past.
Many countries are trying to scale up the deployment of
renewable generation. But their high cost and the
financing challenge are significant barriers to the
transition to a low carbon economy.
New approaches to financing and targeted support for
renewable generation are needed to get back onto a low
carbon pathway.
PwC
Page 4 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Low Carbon Economy Index
Introduction
Achieving the rates of decarbonisation needed to stay within the 2 degrees target agreed by governments in
Cancun in 20101 requires a revolution in the way the world produces and uses energy. A transformation in
financing will also be necessary to achieve the transition at the scale and speed needed.
PwC published the first Low Carbon Economy Index ahead of the COP152 in Copenhagen, 2009. This looked at
the progress of the G20 economies against a 2000-based carbon budget estimated by PwC.3
Carbon intensity is our preferred metric for analysing countries’ movements towards a low carbon economy, as
it accounts for expected economic growth, and can generate comparable targets. The carbon intensity of an
economy is the emissions per unit of GDP and is affected by a country’s fuel mix, energy efficiency and the
proportion of industrial versus service sectors.
Since COP 16 in Cancun, there has been an increasing focus on the cost of meeting the low carbon challenge and
raising the capital required to finance it. This year’s Low Carbon Economy Index focuses on this global
financing gap and the reforms that might help to fill it.
In section one we present our analysis of economic and emissions growth and ask whether we are decarbonising
fast enough. The second section asks are how much it will cost and can we afford it. We highlight the global
financing gap, and focus on efforts to increase low carbon generation in the UK and South Africa. Our report
concludes by outlining some steps that could be taken to help meet the low carbon challenge.
Included in a COP16 decision for the first time
United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change (UNFCCC) Fifteenth Conference of the Parties
3 See Appendix for details
1
2
PwC
Page 5 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
1. LCEI results and analysis
In Cancun last year, governments agreed to limit global warming to 2 degrees Celsius. Achieving this will
require deep reductions in GHG emissions as well as the decoupling of emissions growth from economic
growth. In the last 10 years, most countries have reduced the carbon intensity of their economies – albeit too
slowly (at on average 0.7% per year). In 2010, however, this decarbonisation trend went into reverse.
In 2010, in addition to global emissions reaching their highest level in absolute terms, the carbon intensity of
the global economy increased by 0.6%; emissions rose faster than GDP growth coming out of the 2008-09
recession (5.8% versus 5.1%). Last year our modelling showed that a 4.7% reduction in carbon intensity globally
was necessary to stay on the path to a low carbon economy in 20504. This year, only a decarbonisation rate of at
least 4.8% every year will meet the 2 degrees target. The longer the delay in significant action to tackle
emissions growth, the steeper the path becomes to stay on track with a 2 degrees target.
There are two reasons for this dirty recovery. First, there was the rapid growth of developing economies with
typically higher carbon intensities. Given their income levels, higher levels of carbon intensity are to be
expected, and so their increasing prominence in the global carbon intensity index will increase the overall
average.
More significantly, many of the G20 countries (both developed and developing) saw an increase in the carbon
intensity of their economies in 2010: a real dirty recovery for those economies that had been in recession in
2009. This trend towards higher carbon intensity may have several explanations including the cold winters in
the northern hemisphere at the beginning and end of 2010, the fall in the price of coal relative to gas, and a
drop in renewable energy deployment.
Table 1 outlines these results, showing that only seven countries in the G20 reduced their carbon intensity in
2010.
4
This differs from the published figure last year (5%) due to revisions of historical data by BP and the World Bank
PwC
Page 6 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Increasing carbon intensity
Reducing carbon
intensity
Table 1 : Results of the Low Carbon Economy Index 2010
Country
Growth in
emissions
Real GDP
growth (PPP)
Rate of
decarbonisation
Low Carbon
Challenge:
decarbonisation
rate to 2050
Australia
-8.2%
3.0%
10.9%
4.9%
Mexico
0.1%
5.5%
5.1%
4.5%
Argentina
4.0%
9.2%
4.8%
4.7%
Turkey
6.2%
8.9%
2.6%
5.1%
South Africa
1.6%
2.8%
1.2%
5.1%
India
9.1%
9.7%
0.5%
4.0%
Canada
2.6%
3.1%
0.4%
5.2%
Italy
1.3%
1.3%
-0%
4.7%
France
1.5%
1.5%
-0%
5.0%
Germany
3.7%
3.6%
-0.1%
6.0%
China
10.4%
10.3%
-0.1%
5.5%
EU
1.9%
1.8%
-0.1%
5.2%
Indonesia
6.6%
6.1%
-0.5%
4.5%
World
5.8%
5.1%
-0.6%
4.8%
US
4.1%
2.9%
-1.2%
5.7%
Japan
6.8%
5.1%
-1.6%
5.3%
Russia
6.1%
4.0%
-2.0%
6.5%
Korea
8.4%
6.2%
-2.1%
7.0%
UK
3.5%
1.3%
-2.2%
5.6%
Saudi Arabia
7.0%
3.8%
-3.2%
Brazil
11.3%
7.5%
-3.5%
6.3%
3.9%
Source: PwC analysis, BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2011, World Bank
The last column of presents indicative targets for major economies as compared with a low carbon development
trajectory modelled appropriately for each country (see appendix for our modelling methodology). This
trajectory provides the baseline for our Low Carbon Challenge (LCC) index, which assesses the annual
reduction in carbon intensity required by 2050. This low carbon pathway, at the global level, is illustrated
below.
PwC
Page 7 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Global Low Carbon Achievement Gap (2010)
Carbon intensity
(tCO2/$m (2010) GDP
500
The world now needs to decarbonise
at 4.8% per year to 2050 to meet the
2°C target
400
300
200
The world decarbonised at 0.7% per
year between 2000 and 2010
100
0
2000
2010
2020
Pathway to a low-carbon economy (2010-based)
2030
2040
2050
Pathway to a low-carbon economy (2000-based)
Source: PwC analysis, BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2011, World Bank
In our model, different economic growth paths are set out for developed and developing economies. Highincome countries are generally expected to have slower economic growth (around 2.1% for the G7), and reduce
emissions in absolute terms. Developing countries are expected to have faster economic growth (around 5.5%)
with economic growth progressively being decoupled from carbon emissions; total emissions are projected to
rise at first and then slowly fall.
This year’s results do not fit with this picture of economic and carbon growth. Not only did six of the G7
countries increase their carbon intensity, but the one that did reduce its carbon intensity – Canada – still
increased its total emissions by a significant amount (2.6%). There were more encouraging signs in the E7.
India made some progress with decoupling carbon from economic growth (achieving a 0.5% reduction in
carbon intensity). But in China, emissions roughly kept pace with economic growth.
There were some exceptions:

Australia showed remarkable progress, with solid growth (3%) accompanied by a record fall in tonnes
of carbon emitted (8.2%).

Mexico showed evidence of decoupling in 2011, attaining high economic growth (5.5%) with near-zero
emissions increases (0.1%).

Argentina may also be starting to decouple, with breakneck growth (9.2%) matched by only a moderate
increase in emissions (4%).
The results from these countries do show that an annual rate of decarbonisation of 4.8% is possible, but it will
be extremely challenging to sustain this every year in every country till 2050.
We can also put the 4.8% target in the context of the past thirty years. Over the period 1980-2010 the carbon
intensity of economies globally declined on average at 1.3% a year (in purchasing power parity terms). This
figure masks much variation between decades and countries. Figures 1 and 2 show changes in carbon intensity
over the past 30 years, for individual countries in the G7 and E7 respectively. Of the G20 countries, there are six
that have decarbonised their economies by an average of at least 3% per year in at least one decade: China,
Russia, Germany, France, Japan and the United Kingdom (see Table 2). China is the only country to have
reduced the carbon intensity of its economy by over 4.8% per year over a decade.
PwC
Page 8 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Figure 1 : Carbon Intensity of the G7 1980-2010 (tCO2/$m (2005 PPP))
1000
800
US
Canada
600
Germany
400
United Kingdom
Japan
200
France
Italy
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
0
Figure 2 : Carbon Intensity of E7 1980-2010 (tCO2/$m (2005 PPP))
3000
China
2000
India
Indonesia
Mexico
1000
Turkey
Brazil
Russian Federation
1980
1981
1982
1983
1984
1985
1986
1987
1988
1989
1990
1991
1992
1993
1994
1995
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
2010
0
PwC
Page 9 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Table 2 : Highest decarbonising economies in the G20 1980-2010
Annual decarbonisation
Country
1980-2010
1980-1990
1990-2000
2000-2010
China
3.8%
3.9%
5.8%
1.6%
Germany
2.7%
3.1%
3.3%
1.6%
United Kingdom
2.6%
2.7%
3.0%
1.9%
France
2.5%
4.2%
1.5%
1.6%
Russia5
1.5%
n.a.
0.1%
3.4%
Japan
1.3%
3.1%
-0.2%
0.9%
Source: PwC analysis, BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2011, World Bank
There are two key messages from this analysis. First, over the whole period, no country has sustained
decarbonisation rates even approaching the 4.8% that is now required. With the exception of China in the
1990s, none of the G20 countries has achieved the 4.8% reduction in any decade since 1980.
Secondly, the six countries that did reduce carbon intensity by more than 3% during individual decades have
done so in unique circumstances only. For example, among the developed countries, France decarbonised at
4.2% during the 1980s by increasing the share of nuclear in the energy mix from 7% to 33%6 (see Figure 3). It is
debateable whether this can be replicated by other countries, especially following the nuclear disaster at
Fukushima earlier this year (see Box 1). The UK decarbonised at 3.0% in the 1990s during a ‘dash’ for gas
power generation which replaced coal generation (see Figure 4).
5
6
Russia is 1989-2010
Source : PwC analysis, BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2011
PwC
Page 10 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Figure 3: Decarbonising at 4.2%: France’s changing
energy mix in the 1980s
Figure 4: Decarbonising at 3%: The UK’s dash for gas in
the 1990s
100%
100%
90%
90%
80%
80%
70%
70%
Renewables
60%
Nuclear
60%
Nuclear
50%
Hydro
50%
Hydro
40%
Coal
30%
Gas
20%
Oil
Coal
40%
Gas
30%
Oil
20%
10%
10%
2000
1999
1998
1997
1996
1995
1994
1993
1992
1991
0%
1990
1990
1989
1988
1987
1986
1985
1984
1983
1982
1981
1980
0%
Source: PwC analysis, BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2011
Box 1: Decarbonising after Fukushima
On 11th March 2011, an earthquake measuring 9.0 on the Richter scale struck off the Eastern coast of Japan.
The damage to Japan’s nuclear infrastructure from the resultant tsunami was significant, with the Fukushima
plant still down eight months later and concerns about the long-term safety of nuclear power lingering.
National policy decisions regarding nuclear energy made in response to the earthquake and damage at the
Fukushima Daiichi power plant have been mixed. In the short term, a number of countries, including Japan,
Italy and Venezuela, have delayed plans for nuclear power generation; at least until safety lessons from the
event can be learned. Germany has closed seven of its oldest plants with immediate effect and has stated that
nuclear power generation in the country will cease by the end of 2022. While Switzerland announced that the
country's five ageing plants will not be replaced and therefore nuclear generation will cease in 2034.
Although current reports suggest that the incident will slow, rather than stop nuclear energy growth, the
immediate closure of nuclear plants and impact on future decisions will have a knock on impact on reducing
global carbon emissions. In the short term, the loss of 7GW of German capacity would require nearly doubling
the country’s renewable energy generation to avoid increases in carbon emissions. Japan has already increased
global demand for Liquefied Natural Gas, with Japanese LNG imports up 20.9% year-on-year in April7. The
knock-on, short-term effects of these developments on the global fuel mix and emissions are highly uncertain at
this stage, but likely to be substantial.
In the longer-term though, some commentators are downplaying the impact, with Germany considered in a
minority in terms of policy response. The International Atomic Energy Agency only reduced its baseline
estimate for nuclear capacity in 2030 by 45GW2. Only an additional 4% of global renewable generation would
be required to fill this gap, which is equivalent to Italy roughly doubling its renewable generation8.
7
http://www.ihs.com/products/global-insight/industry-economic-report.aspx?ID=1065929775
Source: PwC Analysis, BP Statistical Review of World Energy, New Europe Energy online : “IAEA lowers nuclear growth forecast after
Fukushima”. Assumes 80% nuclear capacity factor.
8
PwC
Page 11 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
In the developing countries, China decarbonised the most quickly, notably attaining an average decarbonisation
rate of 5.8% per year during the 1990s. This was driven by significant improvements in energy efficiency and a
shift towards services rather than changes in the fuel mix (see Figure 6). Yet China had a very high starting
point: in the 1980s China’s carbon intensity was five times higher than the other E7 countries (with the
exception of Mexico). The adoption of good energy management practices, alongside rapid economic growth
(as high as 14.2%) and the development of the service sector, simply helped bring this closer to the international
average. Even after this period of decarbonisation, China’s carbon intensity still remains more than double
most other G20 countries.
Similarly, there are particular circumstances which explain Russia’s economic and emissions trajectories –
especially in the 2000s. Russia benefitted from very rapid economic growth in the 2000s of 4.5% per year, but
this was, in part, driven by the increasing value of Russia’s oil exports, which results in emissions in other
countries.
Figure 5 : Russia’s energy intensity 2000-2010
(mtoe/$m GDP)
Figure 6 : China’s energy intensity 1980-2010 (mtoe/$m
GDP)
900
800
700
600
500
400
300
200
100
0
500
400
300
200
100
2010
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2002
2001
2000
0
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
2010
600
Russia Energy Intensity (mtoe/$m)
China Energy Intensity (mtoe/$m)
Source: PwC analysis, BP Statistical Review of World Energy 2011, World Bank
In summary, the results of the Low Carbon Economy Index this year suggest that the move to a low carbon
economy will be a huge challenge, but this has been achieved in exceptional circumstances in some countries in
the past. Historically, rates of over 4.8% have been attained, and this year several countries exceeded the
decarbonisation goal required to limit warming to 2 degrees. However, to consistently achieve 4.8% per year to
2050 will require a revolution in energy supply and use.
To stay within the carbon budget, our model suggests how the fuel mix may have to change and how much
energy intensity has to fall over that period (see Figure 7 and Figure 8). Nuclear and renewable generation will
need to account for around 40% of the energy mix by 2050, and carbon capture and storage will be required for
much of the remaining 60%.
The remainder of this report discusses how much this might cost, and how this transition might be financed.
PwC
Page 12 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Figure 7: Low carbon pathway; required changes in
the fuel mix
Oil consumption
Natural gas consumption
2011
2014
2017
2020
2023
2026
2029
2032
2035
2038
2041
2044
2047
2050
180
160
140
120
100
80
60
40
20
0
2011
2014
2017
2020
2023
2026
2029
2032
2035
2038
2041
2044
2047
2050
100%
90%
80%
70%
60%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
0%
Figure 8: Low carbon pathway; required changes in
energy intensity
Global energy intensity under low-carbon
pathway (mtoe/$m)
Coal consumption
Other primary energy
Source: PwC analysis
PwC
Page 13 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
2. The financing gap
The results of this year’s Low Carbon Economy Index suggest that the world as a whole is following a businessas-usual path, with growth still coupled to carbon emissions. Clearly, part of the explanation revolves around
the high economic cost of low carbon energy, and the difficulty of raising finance for innovative low carbon
business models.
The World Economic Forum and Bloomberg New Energy Finance put this incremental low-carbon funding
requirement at $500 billion per year by 20209. In comparison, actual clean investment last year was estimated
at $243 billion10, less than half the amount required. Hitting the 4.8% per year decarbonisation target will
require a substantial scaling-up of low carbon finance.
There are promising signs of new sources of finance. Following the Copenhagen Accord, developed country
governments have pledged to increase funding to tackle climate change in developing countries, from around
$10 billion each year today to $100bn per year by 2020.
Private investors are also increasingly aware of the investment opportunity; last year’s $243 billion investment
in clean technology was a historical record11, and the number of global renewables deals rose by two-thirds
year-on-year12.
However, the gap between the $243 billion and the required $500 billion will be hard to fill. Although the
number of global renewables deals was up two-thirds between 2009 and 2010, their total value fell from $49
billion to $33 billion. It seems questionable whether the world will be able to more than double clean energy
investment by 2020.
In this section, we present case studies of two countries, South Africa and the UK. Both are reforming their
energy markets in order to meet the low carbon challenge. We outline the challenges they face in doing this, and
in section three, make recommendations for financing a low carbon economy.
2.1
The UK
The UK government has estimated that the low-carbon investment required in the power sector by 2020 is in
the order of £89 billion (see Figure 9). This amount is additional to the £110bn required to simply meet energy
needs with coal and gas. Costs will largely be recouped through consumer bills: average energy bills under the
green transition were forecast by Ofgem to increase from 2009-2020 by around £360, to £1450 (although bills
were forecast to rise by a similar amount anyway due to rising wholesale prices and reduced energy efficiency)13.
Rising bills alone though, will not guarantee that enough capital will be invested in time to meet the
government’s 2020 climate targets; there remains the possibility of a financing gap.
Current annual capital expenditure by the Big 6 utilities in the UK (E.On, RWEnpower, SSE, Scottish Power,
Centrica, and EDF) and National Grid would need to triple to reach the government’s target. Given that the
sector is by its own account, highly ‘leveraged’14, it is unlikely to be able to significantly ramp up investment.
World Economic Forum and Bloomberg New Energy Finance (2011) Green Investing 2011 : Reducing the Cost of Financing
Bloomberg New Energy Finance, excludes M&A activity
11 Bloomberg New Energy Finance. Note that public sector finance played an “unprecedented” role in supporting this figure.
12 PwC Renewables Deals (2011)
13 Ofgem (2009) Project Discovery Energy Market Scenarios
14 House of Commons Energy and Climate Change Committee : Electricity Market Reform : Fourth Report of Session 2010-12
9
10
PwC
Page 14 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
And the UK is also not the only European country with a high funding requirement. The German Government,
for example, has estimated that EUR20billion is required annually to meet its Energiekonzept 2050 targets.15
Alternative forms of funding have the potential to fill this finance gap. It has been suggested to the Electricity
Market Reform committee that pension and insurance funds will contribute significant chunk of the finance16.
But, for these players to invest in UK PLC, green technologies must provide a stable return with limited
downside risk. We examine how this challenge will be met in section three.
Figure 9: Ofgem’s investment forecasts under low-carbon and fossil-fuel based scenarios, as
compared to historical UK capex by National Grid and the Big 6
30
Total £199bn
25
20
15
10
Total £110bn
5
Big 6 and National Grid capital expenditure
2020
2019
2018
2017
2016
2015
2014
2013
2012
2011
2010
2009
0
Green Transition Scenario
Dash for Gas Scenario
Source: PwC analysis, company financial statements. Capex defined as relevant additions to PPE, includes
intangible assets for RWEnpower and Scottish Power.
15
16
BMU “Energy concept for an environmentally friendly, reliable and affordable energy supply” (2010)
House of Commons Energy and Climate Change Committee : Electricity Market Reform : Fourth Report of Session 2010-12
PwC
Page 15 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
2.2
South Africa
In South Africa, the government has outlined its ambition to hit a target of 17.8GW of renewable capacity by
2025. This would represent 9% of total generation (its current share of renewables is 0.2%)17. Based on
estimates of the levelised cost of generation of different renewable technologies, the government has introduced
a subsidy regime of Feed-in Tariffs (ReFIT) to encourage renewable generation.
As is shown in Figure 11, the extra cost of generation is significant. The government will have to pay over five
times the current electricity retail price to incentivise solar photovoltaic generation. Even the cheapest
technology, biomass, will be subsidised at twice the current retail price.
Figure 10: South Africa’s payments for renewable generation under the ReFIT programme (maximum),
versus the current regulated electricity price (2010-11)
400
350
397
300
$/MWh
250
$324/MWh
200
150
$76/MWh
100
50
149
$87/MWh
160
73
0
Current Electricity Price
Biomass
Wind
Solar PV
Source : PwC Analysis, Norton Rose, NERSA, ZAR:USD FY2010/11 average
While this has been successful in attracting renewable energy developers (a Request for Interest in 2010
attracted 384 responses18), it could cost up to$324/MWh for the government compared to procuring electricity
generated mainly from coal from the state-owned utility, Eskom (see Figure 11). The World Economic Forum
stated that meeting the country’s goals for renewable capacity by 2025 will cost significantly more than the
alternative of relying on coal-based generation. They suggest that this will be “in excess of what would be
domestically affordable”19.
As both these case studies illustrate, in both the developed and developing world, low carbon energy can be
expensive. Even where policy offloads this cost to the consumer or the taxpayer, attracting private investors is a
challenge. In Section 3 we consider ways of meeting both the cost and finance challenges.
17
South Africa Integrated Resource Plan (IPR)
http://www.deweyleboeuf.com/~/media/Files/clientalerts/2011/20110318_SouthAfricasRefitProgramme.ashx
18
WEF (2011) Scaling up low carbon infrastructure investments in developing countries – The Critical Mass Initiative. This calculation is
based on an updated target of 20GW by 2020 set by the Ministry of Trade under the South Africa rather than DoE capacity targets for 2030
19
PwC
Page 16 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
3. Moving towards the low
carbon economy
The two main challenges in increasing low carbon generation are the high cost and getting the capital to flow to
low carbon options instead of towards conventional technology. There are three areas where countries can focus
their attention to address these challenges:
1.
2.
3.
‘Win-win’ opportunities, typically in off-grid situations where the conventional generation is higher cost.
Removing regulatory and infrastructure barriers to profitable low carbon business
Using innovative models of finance to attract capital to low carbon business
3.1
Win-win opportunities
The trade-off between cost and carbon is not inevitable. In the developing world, where countries do not have
an existing high carbon infrastructure, there are opportunities for “win-win” investment: cost competitive and
low carbon energy.
This opportunity for renewables is particularly evident in Sub-Saharan African countries that do not have large
scale grid infrastructure and coal or gas fired power stations. Current emissions per head that region are
extremely low, less than one-quarter of the global average, and a twentieth of the average in North America (see
Figure 13). Ensuring that future demand for energy in Africa does not result in higher future emissions is a key
part of ensuring the global Low Carbon Challenge of 4.8% per year is met.
Figure 11: Average carbon emissions per capita, 2000-2007 (tCO2)
North America
Europe & Central Asia
Middle East & North Africa
World
East Asia & Pacific
Latin America & Caribbean
Sub-Saharan Africa
0
5
10
15
20
This lack of incumbent high carbon infrastructure now provides an opportunity for cost competitive low carbon
generation in these developing countries. For example, based on a study of Kenya, Ghana and Ethiopia, The
World Bank (2010) has estimated that wind and biomass have similar, or lower, levelised costs than the
alternative, small scale diesel generation. This finding applies both to stand-alone generation and mini-grids
(see Figure 7). The World Bank’s conclusion is that “the economics of decentralised renewable power may be
compelling for large regions of rural Africa”20.
20 World
Bank Development Research Group, Environment and Energy Team (2010) “The Economics of Renewable Energy Expansion in
Rural Sub-Saharan Africa”
PwC
Page 17 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Figure 12: Levelised costs of stand-alone renewable generation, compared to equivalent diesel generation
500
400
403
$/MWh 300
400
250
200
100
0
Diesel
Biomass
Wind
Source: World Bank (2010) The Economics of Renewable Energy Expansion in Rural Sub-Saharan Africa
Clearly, such opportunities are only present in some circumstances; and in the long-term full grid-based
electrification is desirable. However, in rural and remote areas across the developing world, where renewables
are low cost relative to fossil fuel alternatives, donors and governments should seize these medium-term “winwin” opportunities for low carbon development. This is particularly the case in the Asia Pacific, which is
expected to account for 42% of global middle-class spending by 2020, and nearly 60% by 2030.21
3.2
Addressing key regulatory and infrastructure barriers
The high cost of low carbon energy has been highlighted in Section 2. This cost is not entirely due to the
inherent technological cost of low carbon energy, which will come down over time anyway with economies of
scale and learning effects. There are also institutional and physical barriers that artificially drive up costs for
businesses trying to generate low carbon energy. One study by the World Economic Forum (WEF)22 identified a
series of regulatory and infrastructure barriers, largely revolving around the capacity and coverage of national
grids, and limited coordination, experience and integrated planning on the part of national regulators.
WEF concluded that bringing down the costs of doing low carbon business in emerging markets would require
the following actions:






Appropriate assessment of the country’s renewable resource potential
Transparent, clear, consistent policy
Provision of strategic long term implementation plans with clear capacity targets for different
technologies
Continued reform of electricity market structure e.g. appointment of an independent regulator
Grid infrastructure development
Robust commercial frameworks
In South Africa, the government has made a number of steps towards the costs of doing low carbon business
including introducing a competitive tender process for Independent Power Producers (IPPs), creating an
independent regulator, NERSA (National Energy Regulator of South Africa), and prohibiting the state
electricity utility, Eskom, from generating the target capacity (Eskom must instead enter into a power purchase
agreement with the successful bidder).
21
Kharas (2010) “The emerging middle class in developing countries” OECD development centre
22
Source: WEF (2011) Developing renewable energy capacity – Addressing regulatory and Infrastructure challenges in emerging markets
PwC
Page 18 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
3.3
Innovative finance
Making the business case for low carbon technology is a prerequisite for attracting finance to the sector.
However, it will not ensure it. Government should also focus on financial and risk-based barriers that currently
deter investment. The most challenging of these barriers, identified in a recent WEF report23, include a lack of
confidence in the bankability of Power Purchase Agreements, the small scale of renewable projects, uncertainty
around long-term policy support, and the absence of credit and risk guarantees.
Further, governments should recognise that finance will be increasingly likely to come from unconventional
sources such as pension funds or sovereign wealth funds. Currently, less than 1% of the assets pension and
insurance funds manage are apportioned to green investment. This has been attributed to a range of barriers,
including a lack of appropriate investment vehicles, scale issues, regulatory disincentives and limited expertise
in this area24.
The OECD 25 has suggested that encouraging pension and sovereign funding will require the following actions:
 take subordinated equity or debt positions in low carbon investments,
 provide risk mitigation and issue green bonds,
 review inadvertent barriers to pension fund involvement around investment and solvency regulations, and
 support pension trustee education initiatives.
Finally, governments must aim to maximise the leverage factor of their financial contributions, and get as much
private finance from the public funds as possible. One example of an innovative financing model, which
underpins the European Union’s NER300 programme, is outlined in Box 2.
In the UK, Electricity Market Reform has made some progress towards meeting this goal, through introducing
Contract for Difference Feed-in Tariffs, agreeing to make capacity as well as generation payments, establishing
a Green Investment Bank (GIB), and a Carbon Price Floor (CPF)26. However, further details on implementation
and specific price points are needed to further reduce investor uncertainty and close the finance gap. The £1bn
pledged by the GIB only partially closes the finance gap visible in Figure 10.
In the context of offshore wind for example, Renewables Obligation Certificates (ROCs) and the CPF only go so
far in providing the appropriate investment opportunities in the industry3. Policy must now address specific
issues such as pre-construction financing risk that deter institutional investors from investing in offshore wind.
Appropriate measures to reduce risk include underwriting technology and construction risks via a consumer
levy, regulating offshore assets, and measures to increase returns include increasing the numbers of ROCs
available in the first few years of a project and extending the tax-free allowance on Individual Savings Accounts
on investments in offshore wind.
WEF (2011) Scaling up low carbon infrastructure investments in developing countries – The Critical Mass Initiative
Kaminker and Stewart (2011) “The Role of Pension Funds in Financing Green Growth Initiatives”
25 Kaminker and Stewart (2011) “The Role of Pension Funds in Financing Green Growth Initiatives”
26 PwC Roadmap to reform of the UK Power Sector (2011)
23
24
PwC
Page 19 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Box 2. An example of innovative financing:
NER300
The NER300 programme in the EU is one of the innovative approaches taken to maximize private sector
investment from limited public climate finance. Approximately €4.5 billion will be raised from the sale of 300
million EU carbon allowances held in the New Entrants Reserve of the EU Emissions Trading System and this
will be used to fund carbon capture and storage projects and innovative renewable projects. NER300 is an
innovative financial instrument as because first, it co-funds the cost of the innovation only, secondly, it
leverages private sector investment, and finally, it ring fences public money from the sale of emissions credits to
support low carbon projects.
NER300 supports the funding of only the innovative component of a project – known as the relevant costs. The
calculation of the relevant costs accounts for the additional investment required as well as the operating
benefits from a project (such as feed in tariffs or the carbon price). For CCS projects, the relevant costs would
include costs associated with the capture, transport and storage of the CO2, not the power plant itself. For
renewables projects, costs and benefits are compared to those of a conventional power plant with the same
electricity generation capacity.
NER300 will fund half the relevant costs. The other half, as well as all the conventional costs of the project, will
be funded by a combination of private investment and national government support. The NER300 is therefore
leveraging public funds to incentivise only the innovative aspects of low-carbon energy technologies. By
defining and funding the relevant costs only, NER300 maximises the value for money to the public, and
increases the total number of projects that the EU can support.
The budget for NER300 is ring-fenced from the EU carbon market. Any funds will be raised from carbon
intensive industries covered by the EU Emissions Trading Scheme. This not only reinforces the incentive to
reduce carbon emissions, but also avoids imposing additional costs on taxpayers.
PwC
Page 20 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
4. Concluding remarks
The economic downturn initially caused global emissions to fall. Now total emissions are increasing faster than
economic growth – indicating that during the recovery in 2010, the long term trend of slow decarbonisation has
gone into reverse. Unless economic growth is rapidly decoupled from emissions growth, the prospect of
achieving the 2 degrees goal stated by governments in Cancun appears remote. Delaying action to decouple
emissions from economic growth means that the reductions required in future are steeper and probably more
costly.
The British Chancellor, George Osborne, said: “we will not save the world by putting the UK out of business”.
Rapid low carbon economic growth is required to tackle climate change, but not at any cost. There is a risk that
consumers will object to climate change action if the cost, passed on through fuel and electricity bills, is
excessive. Currently, in many countries, low carbon generation requires substantial government subsidy or
market reform to make them viable.
One exception to this could be in rural areas of developing countries which are off-grid. Rural electrification,
particularly in sub-Saharan Africa, will be instrumental in achieving broader development goals. In these areas,
conventional power generation may come from expensive and small scale diesel generation – so here,
renewable technologies may be competitive with the fossil fuel alternative. In addition to green jobs and
economic growth, the low carbon pathway, in this context. offers the potential to improve access to mobile
phones, provide clean lighting and improve indoor air quality.
Addressing some of the institutional and risk-related barriers to these technologies is necessary, but not
sufficient for large scale economy-wide deployment. Innovative financing mechanisms, such as NER300 which
leverages private finance with public funding, and other targeted incentives are necessary to make the
transition to a low carbon economy viable and affordable.
PwC
Page 21 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Appendix: Methodology and
additional modelling results
PwC Macroeconomic Model
The study focuses on the G20 economies with grossed-up estimates for the world as a whole:

G7 economies (US, Japan, Germany, UK, France, Italy, Canada)

E7 economies which covers the BRICs (Brazil, Russia, India and China), and Indonesia, Mexico and Turkey

Other G20 (Australia, Korea, EU, South Africa, Saudi Arabia, Argentina)
The study draws on long-term GDP projections from an updated version of PwC’s “World in 2050” model,
which is based on a long-term GDP growth model structure.
Each country is modelled individually but connected with linkages via US productivity growth (known as the
global technological frontier). Each country is driven by a Cobb-Douglas production function with growth
driven by:

Investment in physical capital

Working age population growth (UN projections)

Investment in human capital (rising average education levels)

Catch-up with US productivity levels (at varying rates)
Real exchange rates will also vary with relative productivity growth.
The results are not forecasts, but rather indicate growth potential assuming broadly growth-friendly policies are
followed and no major disasters (e.g. nuclear war, radical climate change before 2050).
The study considers energy-related carbon emissions, driven by a series of assumptions including the primary
energy intensity and fuel mix share.
GDP model
assumptions
Primary energy
to GDP intensity
assumptions
Fuel mix share
assumptions
GDP (at PPP)
projections
from PwC
model to 2050
Primary energy
consumption
projections
Oil, gas, coal, other
primary energy
consumption
projections
Unit carbon
emissions by
fossil fuel type
Carbon emission
projections to 2050
(by country and
at global level)
Average CO2 levels
in atmosphere (ppm)
Note: all projections done by country then aggregated to global level
PwC
Page 22 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
Business as Usual (BAU) scenario
A BAU scenario is constructed assuming

Energy efficiency improvements in line with historic trends (around 1.5% per year with country variations)

Stable fuel mix

No carbon capture and storage (CCS)
This is NOT intended as being the most likely scenario, just a reasonable benchmark which serves as a starting
point for constructing other scenarios.
Greener Growth plus CCS (GG+CCS) scenario
This is intended to be a very challenging but technically feasible scenario on which the LCE index is based.
In deriving the global carbon budget, we adopted the general consensus of aiming for global CO2e
concentrations to stabilise around 450ppm by 2100. This broadly corresponds to a peaking of concentration by
2050 at around 515ppm and then declining towards 450 ppm by the end of the century. Climate scientists
broadly agree that this level of greenhouse gas concentration stabilisation will provide a fair chance of limiting
the increase in global average temperature to around 2oC.
The three key sets of assumptions which underpin this scenario in terms of energy-related carbon emissions at
global and country level are discussed in turn below. Additional assumptions at global level for carbon
emissions from land use change and forestry are then discussed later together with assumptions on natural
carbon sink capacity at global level.
1. Energy intensity improvements significantly in excess of historic trends
Declines in the ratio of primary energy consumption to GDP (‘energy intensity’) are assumed to average 3% per
year at the global level between 2010 and 2050, which is almost twice the historic average since 1980 and seems
to be the limit of what might reasonably be achievable in this area. All countries are assumed to converge on
this 3% per year achievement trend from 2025 onwards, but with short term country variations up to 2025. For
example for this earlier period from 2010-24, we assume that:

China (4% pa) has one of the most ambitious scope for improvement, which reflects it higher initial level of
energy intensity and the emphasis that the Chinese government has placed on improving energy efficiency
since 2005, which is expected to remain a major focus of climate change policy in that country;

the US (3.5%) is also assumed to have high rates of energy efficiency improvements, as it has one of the
highest energy intensity of major advanced economies and so the most potential scope to reduce this
intensity level, for example through much tougher standards on automotive fuel efficiency levels;

the EU (2.7% pa) is assumed to have a somewhat lower, but still ambitious, potential to improve its energy
intensity levels; nonetheless, this would still require a significantly better performance than the historic EU
average trend improvement rate; and

India (2% pa) is seen as having the least scope for energy intensity improvements in the next 15 years given
that it is starting from a much lower level than China and has still got further to go on its industrialisation
process, which will inevitably tend to create some headwind against very rapid energy intensity
improvements; nonetheless, a 2% per year improvement by India would still be above the global average
rate of improvement in 1980-2009, so it is still a challenging prospect.
We make individual assumptions here for all of the G20 countries based on the similar considerations as
outlined above (which dominate the overall global picture as described earlier in the report).
PwC
Page 23 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
2. Shift from fossil fuels to nuclear and renewables
At the global level, we assume a progressive shift in fuel mix away from coal and oil towards nuclear and
renewables for the period 2010 to 2050. Trends in the share of natural gas are more mixed: with falling trends
for the advanced economies but to rise for China and India where they are starting from low levels.
Overall, the global share of primary energy accounted for by nuclear and renewables27 is assumed to rise to
around 40% by 2050 in this scenario, which is very challenging but aligned with levels projected by previous
studies by the IEA and others. Key assumptions for the key economies for each fossil fuel are as follows:

Coal: for the US, the share of coal in the fuel mix is assumed to decline by 0.3 percentage points per year
between 2010 and 2025 and at a faster rate of 0.5 percentage points per year thereafter as renewable
alternatives to coal for electricity generation become more economically attractive; for China, the same rate
of decline is assumed as for the US up to 2025, but an even faster rate of decline of 0.8 percentage points
per year is then assumed after 2025 to reflect the fact that China is starting from a very heavy dependence
on coal and so has more potential to reduce this in the long run as its economy shifts from heavy industry to
services; India, with lower initial level of development is assumed to have potential for less rapid reductions
in its coal share of 0.1 percentage points per year up to 2025, but accelerating to 0.3 percentage points
thereafter; assumptions for the EU countries, vary with Germany (as a relatively heavy coal user) being
assumed to have scope for reductions at the same pace as the US, while France (with its focus on nuclear
power and very little use of coal by comparison) seeing only a token further reduction at a rate of 0.1
percentage points per year throughout the period.

Oil: assumptions here are less varied than for coal to reflect the fact that the oil share of the fuel mix is
more uniform across the major economies than the degree of reliance on coal; we assume a trend rate of
decline in the oil share of 0.3 percentage points up to 2025 and this is assumed to continue thereafter for
China and India; for the US and the EU, we assume that the rate of decline in the oil share accelerates after
2025 to around 0.5-0.6 percentage points per year due to a more fundamental shift away from reliance on
oil in the automotive and other sectors; this may take longer in China and India since car ownership there
will continue to rise after 2025 whereas in the US and EU this may already have reached saturation point by
then (particularly with oil prices potentially rising as supplies pass their peak levels at some point).

Natural Gas: as noted above, China and India currently make little use of natural gas compared to coal in
particular, but this is expected to change with a particularly marked rise in China in the gas share of the
overall fuel mix by around 0.3-0.4 percentage points per year over the period to 2050; for India the
corresponding rate of shift to gas is assumed to be slower but still moving steadily in that direction at an
average of around 0.1-0.2 percentage points per year. In contrast, natural gas fuel mix is assumed to remain
relatively flat in the US and EU up to 2025 and then to decline thereafter at a rate of around 0.2 percentage
points per year as these economies shift increasingly into renewables (and nuclear in some countries).
3. Carbon capture and storage (CCS)
The third key set of assumptions relates to CCS. It is beyond the scope of this study to attempt to do a countryby-country assessment in any depth here, bearing in mind that CCS is at most at an early pilot stage in a few
countries at this time. We therefore make a much simpler assumption here that global CCS capacity builds up
steadily to an emissions reduction of 1.5 GtC (around 5.5GtCO2) between 2015 and 2050. This CCS capacity is
apportioned to each country based on the share of total carbon emissions excluding CCS, which therefore
automatically takes account of the fact that more coal-intensive (and so carbon-intensive) economies will tend
to have more scope to use CCS.
The actual scale and geographical distribution of CCS capacity remains highly uncertain at this very early stage
in its history, so these estimates may be subject to particularly wide margins of uncertainty at this time.
Summary
27For
simplicity the model assumes both nuclear and renewables to have zero carbon emissions, which is not strictly correct but is a
reasonable approximation for our purposes. We therefore do not try to break down fuel mix between nuclear and different types of
renewables.
PwC
Page 24 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
In differentiating countries in the way described above, we aim to generate energy-related carbon emission
pathways that are challenging but fair in terms of recognising the different starting points of each country in
terms of energy intensity and fuel mix and their differing stages of economic development and, in particular,
industrial structure. CCS is then factored in using a consistent proportional formula as described above.
We have also made assumptions on non energy-related emissions and carbon sinks:

Net annual CO2 emissions from land use changes and forestry (LUCF) around 5.8GtCO2 in 2008 declining
to around 1.4GtCO2 by 2020, and then at a slower rate to around just over -4GtCO2 by 2050. Current
estimates on reducing emissions from deforestation and forest degradation (REDD) expect it to deliver
around 5GtCO2 emissions reduction by 2020.

Global absorption capacity of the planet (oceans, forests etc) is around 15 GtCO2 per year and broadly
stable over time.
This scenario therefore has some common features across countries but also some variations to reflect differing
starting points, stages of economic development and energy resource endowments. We have compared this with
the IEA’s 450 scenario for 2030 emissions, giving broadly similar results as the next chart shows. This gives
some reassurance that our GG + CCS scenario, while clearly challenging, is reasonable both at global level and,
broadly speaking, in terms of allocations to major countries/regions.
Further details on the construction of the low carbon achievement index
This index looks at the extent to which countries have consumed their carbon budget for the first half of the 21st
century by 2009. Since it is cumulative global emissions that drive atmospheric CO2 concentrations rather than
emissions in any one year, there is an implied global carbon budget between 2000 and 2050, estimated here at
just under 1,300 GtCO2.
Based on the same cumulative carbon budget, we constructed two GG + CCS scenario pathways beginning from
2000 and 2008. As GDP is also assumed the same in both variants, we can focus on carbon intensity rather
than levels of carbon emissions in the analysis. Our assumptions include:
1.
Same trend rates of decline for each particular country in the fossil fuel shares of primary energy
consumption in 2001-2025 in the 2000-based model and in 2010-25 in the 2009-based model. In both
variants, the 2026-50 trend rates of decline would be the same (but generally higher than the decline rates
up to 2025 as the costs and feasibility of renewable fuels increases).
2. The rate of decline in energy intensity of GDP is set at 3% p.a. for all countries in 2026-50 in both GG + CCS
variants.
3. Set country-specific rates of decline in energy intensity of GDP in 2001-25 to give the same cumulative
2000-50 carbon budgets in both variants (as in point 1 above). For reasons due to rounding, while in most
cases, the levels of carbon emissions in 2050 are similar in the 2000-based and 2008-based scenarios, they
are not necessarily identical.
4. By comparing the projected emissions pathway of 2000 – 2050 under the Greener Growth + CCS scenario
against the actual emissions between 2000 and 2008, the low carbon achievement index compares how
actual carbon intensity performs against a 2000-based low carbon pathway.
PwC
Page 25 of 26
Low carbon economy index 2011
PwC Advisory Services
Green Growth
PwC is a leader in climate change consulting, working with policy makers and companies since 1997 to analyse issues and
develop practical solutions for our clients. In addition to macroeconomic analysis of the kind contained in this report, our
economics practice provides a wide range of services covering competition and regulation issues, litigation support, bids and
business cases, public policy and project appraisals, financial economics, business forecasting and strategy.
For more detail, please visit www.pwc.co.uk/economics or www.pwc.com/sustainability
Contacts
Leo Johnson
Partner, Sustainability and Climate Change
[email protected]
John Hawksworth
Head of Macroeconomics
[email protected]
Richard Gledhill
Global Head of Climate Change and Carbon Markets
[email protected]
Jonathan Grant
Sustainability and Climate Change
[email protected]
Tim Boothman
Sustainability and Climate Change
[email protected]
This publication has been prepared for general guidance on matters of interest
only, and does not constitute professional advice. You should not act upon the
information contained in this publication without obtaining specific
professional advice. No representation or warranty (express or implied) is given
as to the accuracy or completeness of the information contained in this
publication, and, to the extent permitted by law, PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP,
its members, employees and agents do not accept or assume any liability,
responsibility or duty of care for any consequences of you or anyone else acting,
or refraining to act, in reliance on the information contained in this publication
or for any decision based on it.
© 2011 PricewaterhouseCoopers LLP. All rights reserved. “PricewaterhouseCoopers” refers to PricewaterhouseCoopers
LLP (a limited liability partnership in the United Kingdom) or, as the context requires, the PricewaterhouseCoopers global
network or other member firms of the network, each of which is a separate legal entity.